Δυο
ευρωπαίοι εξετάζουν την Ευρώπη (το 2006) και βρίσκουν ότι αν συνεχίσει στους ίδιους
ρυθμούς, η πτώση είναι αναπόφευκτη. Alberto Alesina και Francesco Giavazzi, The Future of Europe, Reform or Decline, MIT Press, 2006).
Μερικά παραδείγματα που δίνουν:
·
Το μέσο ευρωπαϊκό ΑΕΠ αμέσως μετά
τον 2ο ΠΠ ήταν ίσο προς το 42% αυτού των ΗΠΑ. Στα τέλη της δεκαετίας
του 1980 είχε φτάσει στο 80%. Το 2005 έπεσε στο 70%.
·
To 1960 οι δαπάνες Γενικής Κυβέρνησης ήταν 29% του ΑΕΠ
(όσο
το σημερινό των ΗΠΑ), το 1970 ανήλθαν στο 37% και το 1990 στο 50%. Αυτό σήμαινε
αυξημένη φορολογια και μείωση της ανάπτυξης.
·
Από το 2ο ΠΠ και μετά
η Ευρώπη δεν επένδυσε στην τεχνολογική καινοτομία αλλά βασίστηκε σε αντιγραφές
των αμερικανικών καινοτομιών (όπως και η Ιαπωνία και η Κορέα). Σήμερα που η
καινοτομία και όχι αντιγραφή είναι η κινητήριος δύναμη της ανάπτυξης, η Ευρώπη
έχει θέμα.
Αν
και ξεχνούν δομικές ανεπάρκειες του όλου συστήματος τυφλωμένοι/καυλωμένοι από
τον τότε καλπασμό του αμερικάνικου συστήματος που βασίστηκε σε φούσκες για να
αντισταθμίσει την μόνιμη τάση του μονοπωλιακού καπιταλισμού προς στασιμότητα,
γράφουν ένα ωραίο νεοφιλελεύθερο μανιφέστο και σε αρκετά έχουν δίκιο. Το όλον συμπυκνώνεται σε μια τους φράση: A market economy is a market
economy: qualifications are misleading…
The
Future of Europe
Reform or Decline
By Alberto Alesina and Francesco
Giavazzi
Introduction
A
recent poll taken in the European Union identified the
United
States as the biggest enemy of world peace, after Israel
and
North Korea, in that order. In the United States, anti-French
sentiments
are widespread. Cross-Atlantic relationships have rarely
been
at such a low point in the post–World War II era.
It
would be superficial to attribute the cross-Atlantic animosity to
the
European aversion to the current American president, George
W.
Bush, or to the American irritation at the French and German
opposition
to the war in Iraq. The truth is that Americans and Europeans
are
different, think differently, and are becoming more
different.
Europeans
work less, take longer vacations, and retire early.
Americans
choose to work long hours. In August, Paris is a ghost
town,
except for the tourists, and Milan is a ghost town, period; in
August,
New York does not look very different than in any other
month
except for more European tourists. Europeans view job security
and
stability as a fundamental right and a ticket for happiness.
Americans
are willing to endure the ups and downs, the bankruptcies,
and
the unemployment spells as a necessary part of a market
economy.
Europeans tend to hold the same job for most of their life,
Americans
change jobs frequently. Europeans view any cut in
the size of the welfare state as unacceptable.
Americans view tax
increases
as an evil to be avoided at all cost. Europeans view
inequality
as a major problem. Inequality in the United States is on
the rise,
but Americans appear to be willing to live with it. Europeans
believe
that the use of force in international relations should
almost
never (read “never”) be used. Americans believe in the relatively
frequent
use of force. Europe is relatively closed to foreign
immigrants.
America is a country of immigrants. Europeans believe
that
society determines much of an individual’s fortune; Americans
believe
that individuals are responsible for their own fate. Americans
believe
that competition is critical for economic success and
embrace
it. Europeans are prompt to emphasize the benefits of a
Soziale
Marktwirtschaft (a social market economy), a model invented
by
Germany, which means putting restraints on market forces
through
government regulation.
These
differences are becoming more, rather than less, deeprooted.
In the
recent debate in France, ahead of the vote on the European
constitution,
both camps promised they would prevent the
country
from adopting a social system resembling the despised
Anglo-Saxon
“ultra liberalism.” The American form of capitalism
was the
universal enemy; the disagreement was on the best way to
fight it
and be different. Any discussion about economic reform in
Europe is
prefaced by a disclaimer about the superiority of the
European
model compared to the American one. In the German
election
campaign of 2005, the conservative candidate, Angela
Merkel,
promised profound change but committed not to touch the
basic characteristics
of the German social model. All that her opponent
had to do
to avoid defeat was to scare German voters about
the risks
of market liberalism. By doing so, he engineered a phenomenal
last-minute
electoral turnaround. Americans, on the other
hand,
show no inclination toward changing their welfare system
and
making it more similar to the European one.
In this
volume we discuss the problems that confront Europe
using the
rhetorical device of a comparison between Europe and the
United
States along different dimensions. But this is not an academic
book, and
we are not shy in taking sides on the issues we analyze.
We are
very critical of many aspects of the European model. But
let us be
clear. We do not argue that European countries should
simply
copy the United States and adopt identical policies. America
is far
from perfect; on the contrary, it has very serious problems. For
instance,
the American health care system is explosively expensive
and many
Americans do not receive adequate health care. American
inner
cities are an embarrassment, and the correlation between
poverty
and race is disturbing. America has a lot to learn from
Europe.
Some aspects of the European welfare state can ensure
social
solidarity and, when well designed, at relatively low efficiency
cost.
Are we
then saying that there is a “third way” in between the
American
model and the European model? No, or at least not in the
common
way in which this is understood. Those who argue that
there is
a third way—and talk about European reforms but in the
next
sentence emphasize that Europe should be different from the
“American
free market”—are simply fuzzy thinkers, the typical
example
being the German notion of a social market economy. A
market
economy is a market economy: qualifications are misleading.
But,
quite apart from blank and somewhat superficial endorsements
of one
model or another, our view is that Europe should
adopt
very large scale reforms that would make its markets and its
institutions
(such as universities and banks) look much more like
those of
the United States than they are now; of course, these
reforms
do not require the adoption of every aspect of, for instance,
the
American welfare system. The most important lesson that the
United
States can give to Europe is a belief that people respond to
incentives
and most of the time markets work, or at least they work
better
than any other mechanism.
Without
serious, deep, and comprehensive reforms Europe will
inexorably
decline, both economically and politically. Absent
profound
change, in twenty or thirty years the share of Europe
in the
world economy will be significantly lower than it is
today,
and perhaps more important, its political influence will be
much
trimmed. Europeans seem to be living in the dream that
their
past splendor and their current prosperity cannot be lost.
This is a
mistake. A major European decline is indeed a serious
possibility.
Think of
Britain. It took the British people twenty years of economic
and
political decline to realize that their country was about
to
disappear from the world economic and political scene. In 1960,
Britain’s
GDP per capita was 78 percent of US GDP per capita. By
1980, the
ratio had fallen to 67 percent. Eventually Britain’s decline
was
stopped by the policies adopted by Margaret Thatcher: by the
beginning
of the 1990s, the ratio of UK to US GDP per capita had
stabilized
to around 68 percent, although, relative to the United
States,
Britain never recovered the losses it suffered in the 1970s.
(The
percentages cited here are from Penn World Tables, compiled
by the
Center for International Comparisons of the University of
Pennsylvania.)
Europe
emerged from World War II with a level of per capita GDP
that was
less than half that of the United States: 42 percent. In the
first
thirty years after the war, Europe reduced that distance to
one-half.
By the end of the 1980s, its GDP per capita was 80 percent
of the US
level. Since then convergence has stopped. As a matter of
fact in
the last twenty yeas Europe has lost ground: GDP per
capita
today is about 70 percent of the US level, the position Europe
had
reached at the end of the 1970s. One is reminded of Britain in
the
1970s, but we fail to see a new Mrs. Thatcher appearing on the
European
scene.
The
prospect of an economic decline comes out sharper if one
looks at
individual countries. By 1970, Italy had reached a level of
GDP per
capita equal to 68 percent of the US level, a big achievement
for a
country that had started from 30 percent in 1950. By 1990,
the ratio
had reached 80 percent. Today, it is back to 64 percent, the
level of
the mid-1960s. In the same period, from the mid-1960s to
today,
the South Korean GDP per capita has risen, relative to the
United
States, from 12 to 50 percent. If the Korean GDP per capita
keeps
growing, relative to the United States, at the same rate it has
grown
over the past twenty-five years, by 2030, Korea will be richer
than the
United States. It is unlikely that this will happen: the
Korean
growth rate is, at least in part, the result of economic catchup.
The
growth will inevitably slow down as Korea gets richer. But
there is
nothing that can automatically stop Italy’s decline relative
to the
United States. If the relative decline continues at the current
pace, in
twenty-five years Italian GDP per capita will be one-third
that of
the United States. Relative to the United States, Italy will
return to
the conditions of the early 1950s. This doesn’t mean Italy
will be a
poor country. The living standard of its (by then rather
aged)
citizens will continue to be good.
This
raises the issue of whether relative economic decline is really
so bad.
In absolute terms, Europe is rich and it will not become poor
overnight:
the decline will be relative to other countries. Should
Europeans
care? To be concrete, why should a middle-class Frenchman
be
bothered if a middle-class tourist from Korea in Paris will
soon be
able to afford items out of reach for the French themselves?
We
believe that this hypothetical Frenchman should and would care.
First of
all, relative economic power matters in the area of international
relations.
Second, and perhaps more important, a host of economic
and
psychological research shows that individuals’ happiness
depends
not only on their own income but also on their income relative
to
others; it also depends on the growth of individual income.
Third,
societies that stop growing develop a “culture of stagnation,”
which can
have a host of negative social consequences, a theme
explored
in a recent book by Harvard economist Benjamin Friedman.
Sure our
hypothetical Frenchman will enjoy his longer vacations and
may criticize the hard-working Korean, but leisure
increases happiness only to a point. In addition we should not forget that
poverty has
not been
completely eradicated from Europe and a sustained rate of
growth is
the best cure for poverty. Generous welfare provisions
become
difficult to sustain in a slow growing economy.
In fact
relative decline can turn into absolute decline. The experience
of
Argentina stands as a specter over Europe. At the beginning
of the
last century Argentina was among the richest countries
in the
world, twice as rich as Italy and about as rich as France. Then
the world
changed, but Argentineans kept thinking that exporting
corn and
beef was enough to remain rich. For a long time, until the
crisis of
2001, most Argentineans were unaware of—or refused to
recognize—the
depth of their problem. When the crisis broke out
all at
once, Argentineans found themselves poor.
Are
Europeans aware of these unpleasant possibilities? In our
view, not
entirely. But could they be right in not worrying? Certainly
history
suggests caution in making long-run predictions about
winners
and losers. In the late 1970s Japan was the model country
and many
thought that the United States was doomed: eventually
exactly
the opposite happened. In the same decade pundits were
talking
about the American decline, pointing to the TV images of
long
lines at the gas station, American hostages in Iran, and to the
“irreversible”
decline in American productivity. Today all of this
seems far
away—except, unfortunately, for hostages, although not
in Iran.
Will we be saying the same thing in twenty years about
wrong
predictions of European doom and gloom made in 2006?
May be,
but lacking comprehensive reforms, these gloomy predictions
are
likely to become true.
What
happened to Europe? In the 1960s Europe looked like a
model for
the world. With rapid growth and cohesive societies,
Europeans
were among the happiest in the world. Why did the
miracle
abruptly come to an end?
There are
two possible explanations. The
first points to politics
and the
other to technology. We begin with politics. In the 1950s and
1960s
Europeans worked very hard. Many European cities had been
leveled
during World War II. Factories were destroyed, and human
capital
was depleted by war casualties. This was not the time to
think
about leisure and consumption. Europeans had to dig in their
heels and
start to rebuild. By the end of the 1960s their resolve had
success.
Europeans could now raise their thoughts to the quality of
their
lives. Also the late 1960s was a period of political turmoil.
From
universities to factories, Europeans demanded less work
with
equal pay, labor regulations against firings, free education
and free
health care for everyone, and generous pensions to be
enjoyed
earlier in life. In the end, governments delivered what
the
people asked. European economies had been growing fast,
and there
seemed to be enough resources to accommodate all
demands.
Then came the oil crisis and at the same time, at least in
some
countries such as Germany and Italy, the fight for change
became tough.
To prevent students and workers from being lured
by the
call of the extreme left—these were the years of Bader
Meinhof
and the Red Brigades—governments kept accommodating
even
after it had become clear that the resources were no
longer
there. In the 1970s the welfare state was paid for through
inflation
and in the 1980s by building up public debt. From those
years
Europe inherited large governments and the high taxes
needed to
pay for it. In 1960, total government spending (the
average
for the pre-enlargement EU 15 countries) was 29 percent of
GDP (the
level of the United States today); in 1970, it was 37; in
1980, it
was 47; and in 1990, it was 50 percent of GDP. The accompanying
increase
in taxes depressed growth. Some other factors, the
oil shock
in particular, contributed as well and compounded the
fiscal
deficiencies.
Had
Europe continued to grow as in the 1950s and 1960s, the
welfare
demands of the 1970s could have been accommodated with
more
limited increases in tax rates. But in the 1970s the engine that
until
then had provided growth stopped working, and this is where
the
explanation based on technology comes into place. As economists
Daron
Acemoglu, Philippe Aghion, and Fabrizio Zilibotti
argue in
their academic work, European growth in the 1960s was—
as Japan
and Korea experienced later—largely of the catch-up type.
Europeans
started off, after World War II, far from the technological
frontier:
imitation of the best US technologies was enough for a
fast
pickup. As we will discuss later in the book, imitation works
well with
large incumbent and entrenched firms, a bank-centered
financial
system, long-term relationships, a slow turnover of managers,
stable
ownership of firms, and a hands-on approach by the
government.
Industrial policy did work in the 1960s in Europe, as
it did
later in Korea and Japan. But when Europe came closer to the
technological
frontier, and innovation rather than imitation became
the
critical factor for growth, Europe found itself ill prepared. The
very
institutions that had been responsible for the success of the
1960s
became an obstacle to growth after the 1970s. Rather than
speed up
the destruction of old firms and favor the creation of new,
innovative
enterprises, Europeans kept on protecting incumbents
and
dreaming up industrial policy.
It is
hard to see how Europe can turn around if it does not
change
profoundly, but we do not see enough energy for
reforms.
Germany has 5 million unemployed, the highest number
since the
Weimar Republic, but we see acquiescence rather
than
change. Italy and Portugal are falling behind even relative
to
Germany: exports are falling and productivity growth has
virtually
stopped. In both countries the political system is incapable
of
delivering reforms. What we see instead of reforms, are the
attempts
of insiders to protect themselves from the effects of economic
integration
and the globalization of markets. France is
moving in
a protectionist direction, that of the French fortress,
the
Asterix village. French farmers are heavily protected from the
competition
of farmers from developing countries. In Italy many
believe
that only tariffs can save their country from Chinese competition
especially
in the textile sector. These protectionist tendencies
are
worrisome.
The
reader should be aware of oversimplifications. To begin with,
we say
Europe but we really mean continental Western Europe. In
many
dimensions Europeans have, vis-à-vis the United Kingdom,
reactions
that are similar to those elicited by the United States. The
French
veto on the proposed new European constitution was partly
a vote
against Tony Blair’s alleged plans to reform the European
social
model along Anglo-Saxon lines. In Central and Eastern
Europe
some countries are adopting models quite different from
those of
continental Western Europe and closer to the Anglo-Saxon
type.
Even within Western Europe there are many differences. The
Scandinavian
countries, after suffering a deep crisis in the early
1990s,
have been able to combine a far-reaching welfare state with
market
flexibility and decent growth. It is too early to say whether
their
current performance will be a long-lasting success. Hailing
Nordic
countries as an example of the superiority of the European
economic
model over that of the United States—an argument one
often
hears in Europe—is at least premature, but no doubt something
very
important is happening there. Unfortunately, the larger
European
countries—France, Germany, Italy, and Spain—do not
show the
political will and capability of adopting Nordic policies.
Moreover
the social cohesions and “social capital” so diffuse in
Nordic
countries and that greatly help their systems work well are
lacking
in southern Europe.
Interestingly,
while Americans and Europeans have different
views,
they both seem happy with the societies in which they live.
A recent
poll asked people how they felt about their quality of life:
eight
European countries rank above the United States and seven
below,
with no clear pattern: Italy and Spain rank 8th and 10th,
the
United States 13th, France and Germany 25th and 26th. This
suggests
that Americans and Europeans pretty much get what they
like:
they are unlikely to want to switch sides of the Atlantic. By the
way, even
in Argentina most people claimed to be happy right up
to the
day of the crisis!
So is
there no problem? Well, yes and no. It is certainly true that
by and
large European policies reflect the will of the electorate,
as they
should in democracies. Europeans are certainly not free
marketers
trapped by interventionist politicians. However,
the
Europeans’ aversion to market liberalism is often strategically
fostered
by groups of insiders who benefit from market
protection.
This is indeed one of the major themes of this
book.
In recent
years numerous signs of dissatisfaction (still not well
channeled
politically) have been arising in France, Germany,
and
Italy. In all three cases one perceives frustration with an inability
to
implement reforms that are urgently needed. More important,
lack of
concern for serious reforms may simply reflect a failure
to
understand what is coming. The European decline is a slow
process,
and this makes reforms more difficult politically to
accomplish.
Crises often generate the impetus for reform, a
slow
decline less so. In Latin America, for instance, certain countries,
and
especially Chile, emerged from a near catastrophic crisis
in the
1970s and a period of dictatorship with a new vigor. The
reforms
in Chile have turned its emerging economy into one of the
most
successful in Latin America. From the 1950s onward Europe
had no
big crises, no hyperinflation nor hyper recession. An old
saying
goes, if you put a frog in cold water and start warming the
water
slowly until it boils, the frog dies. If you throw a frog in hot
water, it
jumps out and lives. Europe is that frog in slowly warming
water.
Look at
the facts. Partly because of high taxes, generous pensions,
high
unemployment benefits, and unions’ insistence for fewer
hours of
work and partly because of attitudes, Europeans work less
and less.
Italian “kids” leave college at age 27; then they spend a
couple of
years looking for a job, they work 30 years, and eventually
they
retire at 60 and live until they are 90. The French have
obtained
a 35-hour week and in May and August very few are at
work in
France. In Germany peak hour traffic on a Friday is 2 pm.
You can’t
grow very fast if you work fewer and fewer hours per
person,
unless your productivity grows at extraordinary rates. For
this to
happen, you need research and development and competitive
universities,
not to mention truly competitive product markets
that
promote the quick adoption of new technologies. Europe is
deficient
in all these dimensions. Rather than building upon its most
talented
young people, it does very little to stop them from migrating
to the
United States, tempted by US universities and US hightech
firms.
About one-third of Harvard’s economics department
is
Europeans who have fled their countries’ troubled universities.
Western
Europe, instead of trying to attract the most talented
youths
from India, China, and Eastern Europe, restricts migration.
The
immigrants allowed are not the smart people who in the United
States
have created the many innovative start-ups. The best
educated
Central and Eastern Europeans are flying over Western
Europe
and going to the United States. “Wait ten years to open your
borders
to my fellow citizens,” recently said the then Romanian
foreign
minister, “and every smart Romanian engineer will have
migrated
to the United States: what you’ll get will be our uneducated
peasants.”
Europeans
are growing older. Fertility rates are exceptionally
low.
Europe won’t thrive if only a few people work to support an
increasing
number of retirees. The closed borders and irrational
immigration
policies promise to make the European aging populations
amid low
birth rates harder to sustain. These two demographic
trends
will seriously strain European budgets.
Economic
decline and political decline go hand in hand. Because
of its
large social spending and the low growth rate, Europe cannot
support a
powerful military. Sooner rather than later Europe will
lose its
powerful role in international organizations. Already today
people around
the world, especially in Asia, are wondering why
France
and Britain should have permanent seats in the UN Security
Council.
Countries like China and India with population sizes
orders of
magnitudes larger than France, Britain, and Germany
combined
will soon demand and obtain more power in world
politics,
and rightly so. At the moment these countries are determined
to work
hard and become rich. Pretty soon they will succeed
and call
for more recognition at the political tables of world organizations.
European
countries will have to move over.
The
organization and allocation of power in international organizations,
from the
UN to the IMF and the G7 (now G8) meetings,
still
reflects a post–Second World War equilibrium that has become
obsolete.
At that time Germany and Japan were the defeated aggressors;
the
Soviets were a threat, Germany was divided and a wall
was about
to be built. Much of the then-called Third World was
either
recently independent or a colony but still very poor. Times
have
changed: there were 74 independent countries in the world in
1945, and
there are 193 today. Communism outside of China, Cuba,
and North
Korea is popular only in Parisian cafés; Germany is
reunited;
the Third World is growing faster than the First World.
Computer
software is now mostly developed in Bangalore; graduate
programs
in the United States, including business schools, admit
thousands
of smart Asian students. Times have changed; France
and
Britain continue to have permanent seats on the UN Security
Council
and Italy, not China, is part of the G7. Not for long.
Europe’s
lack of military spending also affects growth directly,
since
much of cutting edge technology is developed in military
contracts.
In the United States many high-tech firms, if they are
really
good, thrive thanks to contracts with the Pentagon. In Europe
instead
of military contracts firms often receive state subsidies,
which is
a much less efficient way of stimulating research and innovation.
Europe
could prevent its rapid military and political decline
by
pulling together resources (political and military) with a true
foreign
policy through the European Union. But recent experience
suggests
that European countries are very far from reaching any
resemblance
of this, and in fact they are walking away from any
further
political integration.
So is the
Untied States of Europe a way out of Europe’s decline?
Yes and
no. As an economic area the European Union has worked
relatively
well. As a form of political union, however, the rapid
annihilation
of the proposed constitution has shown the severe
limits of
this process. The idea of a European political union that
balances
the United States in the international arena seems less and
less
realistic every day.
The
hurdles that stand in the way of a United Europe also stem
from one
of Europe’s main advantages: its diversity—diversity of
language,
of culture, of historical experience, and of lifestyle. Diversity
may
prevent Europe from exploiting the potential of unity, but
a diverse
society could be in a better position to adapt to change.
In a
rapidly changing world this could be Europe’s most important
asset.
Europe should embrace diversity both within its ranks and
with
reference to non-Europeans. Instead, Brussels’ insistence on
coordination
and uniformity is in sharp contrast with the “Let a
thousand
flowers bloom” view of the world. In the area of diversity
Europeans
could learn from the Unites States. Americans have
had a
history of dealing with racial and ethnic diversity, and it is as
both an
asset and a liability. It is an asset because being a successful
melting
pot is what has made America great. It is a liability
because
many of the social problems in the United States are associated
with race
relations. Europe has the opportunity to learn from
this
experience, or it can sit back and pontificate about American
failings.
The view of French youths of African descent rioting in
Paris in
November 2005 shocked the same Parisian intellectuals
who led
the May 68 riots. Troubling as these riots seemed, they are,
unfortunately,
the wave of the future.
Europe is
at a crossroad. It can continue with business as usual
and
accept a slow but permanent decline. Or it can initiate reforms.
Change is
difficult, of course, where attitudes and institutions have
deep
roots in history and in political and intellectual traditions. But
change is
needed if an economic decline is to be avoided. Today the
choice is
still readily available; another decade of decline may
foreclose
this option.
Often the
Europeans who worry about Europe’s problems
respond
by proposing a long list of very detailed policies. Often
they call
for more public spending on infrastructure, education,
industrial
policies, and support for depressed areas. Our view is
different.
Europe does not need more public money in a myriad of
programs.
Europe needs reforms that create incentives and make its
people
willing to work hard and longer, take risks, and innovate.
Europe
needs more competition, not more public infrastructures.
European
universities need more “market incentives,” not more
public
money. European firms need lower taxes, less heavily regulated
labor
markets, and better functioning product markets, not
more
subsidies and protection. This does not mean that Europe
simply
needs to adopt the entire US model. Indeed there are aspects
of the
European welfare state that are efficient and should be preserved.
But too
often the benefits to overprotected insiders get
precedence
over the needs of the general public and, in particular,
at a cost
to the younger generation.
Some
observers are talking about the twenty-first century being
the
European century, the same as the twentieth century was the
American
century. We take a more skeptical view: there is as good
a chance
that the twenty-first century will be the century of European
decline.
We hope to be proved wrong.
Δεν υπάρχουν σχόλια:
Δημοσίευση σχολίου